ROSS HARVEY: Why this year’s economics Nobel matters for Africa
Winning economists have contributed hugely to the field by boosting democracy
22 October 2024 - 05:00
byRoss Harvey
Support our award-winning journalism. The Premium package (digital only) is R30 for the first month and thereafter you pay R129 p/m now ad-free for all subscribers.
Academy of Sciences officials Hans Ellegren, Jakob Svensson and Jan Teorell award the Swedish Riksbank’s prize in economic science to Daron Acemoglu, Simon Johnson and James A Robinson. Picture: REUTERS/TOM LITTLE
One of my favourite economists has eventually won a Nobel prize, with Simon Johnson and James Robinson. Daron Acemoglu’s work has shaped my outlook on development perhaps more than any other thinker.
Their prize comes 23 years after the authors’ epic paper “The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation” was published in the American Economic Review in 2001. Using a novel econometric technique, they “instrumented” settler mortality (among European colonisers) to understand the nature of the relationship between institutional quality and economic outcomes. The upshot is that where colonial settlers’ survival rates were higher, the institutions they built produced more broad-based prosperity than in other areas (often wealthier in natural resource abundance) where mortality was higher.
You can imagine that the findings have proved controversial. I remember the 2004 editions of the Journal of Economic Growth, for instance, in which several scholars debated the merits of the argument. Glaeser and his co-authors argued, on the one hand, that instrumenting settler mortality was capturing the more basic effect of human capital, and that high levels thereof and good policies were what propelled countries out of poverty. Dani Rodrik and his co-authors, on the other hand, found that the quality of institutions “trumps everything else” in respect of factors explaining divergent economic outcomes.
Acemoglu and Robinson expanded on the big idea of their 2001 work in an epic 2012 book, Why Nations Fail. For anyone looking to understand why institutional quality really is of primary importance for determining long-run economic outcomes, the book is key reading. Many authors favoured geographic and biological explanations; others preferred cultural factors. But Why Nations Fail shows in digestible detail why these other factors are unsatisfactory in their explanatory power.
Political consequences
Institutions determine how nations make use (or not) of their peculiar geographies and influence the evolution of societal norms through the ecological incentives they provide. Extractive institutions result in the literal extraction of rents at the expense of broad-based growth for the benefit of elite insiders (think “state capture” in SA). Inclusive institutions on the other hand, ensure broad-based property rights and uphold civil liberties. These produce sustainable, long-term development.
Perhaps my favourite paper of Acemoglu and Robinson’s is “Economics vs Politics: Pitfalls of Policy Advice” of 2013. Too many economists advocate for public policy that simply aims to reduce or remove “market failures and policy distortions”, but this ignores the impact of politics. In their words: “the extant political equilibrium may crucially depend on the presence of the market failure. Economic reforms implemented without an understanding of their political consequences, rather than promoting economic efficiency can significantly reduce it.”
This work dovetailed with the impressive work of another Nobel laureate, Douglass North, whose book Violence and Social Orders with John Wallis and Barry Weingast, was published in 2009. Acemoglu and Robinson write that the North et al book “also indirectly underscores that the ‘good economics is good politics’ dictum is fallacious by providing several counterexamples in the context of what they call the ‘natural state’,” in which warring elites construct often highly inefficient elite bargains to generate a shared rent pool in exchange for abandoning violence towards one another. The upshot is that policy impositions that are incentive-incompatible with the distribution of political power are unlikely to gain traction.
Delivers both
For this reason, many analysts have argued that democracy does not work for Africa as it has not produced an appropriate economic dividend. Some see it as a Western imposition that is incongruent with postindependence political equilibriums. Others posit, more condescendingly, that African countries are not yet ready for democracy. Indeed, in the context of global democratic backsliding, what should we say to this?
Acemoglu and Robinson’s 2019 book, The Narrow Corridor, shows that democracy is pivotal to the two arms of governance required for sustained broad-based development, independent of context. Imagine two axes: vertically, we have government effectiveness (or the strength and sophistication of the state); and horizontally we have the power of citizens (or the ability of citizens to hold Hobbes’ Leviathan to account). Democracy is the only political system that delivers both.
There are numerous states where governments are relatively effective, but citizens are repressed. These nations will not see the dividends of broad-based economic prosperity. China, for instance, will grow old before it grows rich. Dictators make strategic mistakes (threaten Taiwan, support Russia and North Korea and so on), cook the books and rewrite history to maintain power and keep citizens in subjugation. This arrangement may at first seem efficient but will prove deleterious in the long run.
To dispel further doubts about the causal direction and nature of the relationship between democracy and economic growth, Acemoglu and Robinson, collaborating with Suresh Naidu and Pascual Restrepo, published a 2019 paper in the Journal of Political Economy unequivocally titled “Democracy Does Cause Growth”. In their words: “Our baseline results show that democratisations increase GDP per capita by about 20% in the long run ... The effects are similar across different levels of development and appear to be driven by greater investments in capital, schooling and health.”
Citizen strength
For this reason it continues to be our firmly held belief at Good Governance Africa that democracy is worth fighting for. Our theory of change, informed by The Narrow Corridor, is that strengthening government effectiveness and empowering citizens simultaneously will produce the economic dynamism required to address structural unemployment and poverty. That is because government effectiveness is a function of bureaucratic quality, robust rule of law, effective control of corruption and political stability.
In turn, citizen strength is a function of the extent to which the state upholds civil liberties such as academic freedom, and the civil liberties of expression and association. Only democracy provides the mechanisms, if often imperfect (there is not only one type of democracy), for citizens to demand delivery, and to hold the government to account if it fails to do so.
We live in an international order in which there is no effective supranational body. In the words of Thucydides, “the strong do as they will, and the weak suffer as they must”. The only way to prevent the “weak” from suffering (in continued poverty) is to empower citizens to stand up to the state. That requires building domestic institutions that create the appropriate ecological incentives for a political equilibrium that is responsive to citizens, and an economic equilibrium that delivers dividends for them. International efforts to complement this are to be welcomed, but they should never be seen as replacements.
Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson have made a profound contribution to the fields of economics and political economy. We should take their work seriously as we think about the most effective way to build narrow corridors in our respective countries.
• Harvey is director of research & programmes at Good Governance Africa.
Support our award-winning journalism. The Premium package (digital only) is R30 for the first month and thereafter you pay R129 p/m now ad-free for all subscribers.
ROSS HARVEY: Why this year’s economics Nobel matters for Africa
Winning economists have contributed hugely to the field by boosting democracy
One of my favourite economists has eventually won a Nobel prize, with Simon Johnson and James Robinson. Daron Acemoglu’s work has shaped my outlook on development perhaps more than any other thinker.
Their prize comes 23 years after the authors’ epic paper “The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation” was published in the American Economic Review in 2001. Using a novel econometric technique, they “instrumented” settler mortality (among European colonisers) to understand the nature of the relationship between institutional quality and economic outcomes. The upshot is that where colonial settlers’ survival rates were higher, the institutions they built produced more broad-based prosperity than in other areas (often wealthier in natural resource abundance) where mortality was higher.
You can imagine that the findings have proved controversial. I remember the 2004 editions of the Journal of Economic Growth, for instance, in which several scholars debated the merits of the argument. Glaeser and his co-authors argued, on the one hand, that instrumenting settler mortality was capturing the more basic effect of human capital, and that high levels thereof and good policies were what propelled countries out of poverty. Dani Rodrik and his co-authors, on the other hand, found that the quality of institutions “trumps everything else” in respect of factors explaining divergent economic outcomes.
Acemoglu and Robinson expanded on the big idea of their 2001 work in an epic 2012 book, Why Nations Fail. For anyone looking to understand why institutional quality really is of primary importance for determining long-run economic outcomes, the book is key reading. Many authors favoured geographic and biological explanations; others preferred cultural factors. But Why Nations Fail shows in digestible detail why these other factors are unsatisfactory in their explanatory power.
Political consequences
Institutions determine how nations make use (or not) of their peculiar geographies and influence the evolution of societal norms through the ecological incentives they provide. Extractive institutions result in the literal extraction of rents at the expense of broad-based growth for the benefit of elite insiders (think “state capture” in SA). Inclusive institutions on the other hand, ensure broad-based property rights and uphold civil liberties. These produce sustainable, long-term development.
Perhaps my favourite paper of Acemoglu and Robinson’s is “Economics vs Politics: Pitfalls of Policy Advice” of 2013. Too many economists advocate for public policy that simply aims to reduce or remove “market failures and policy distortions”, but this ignores the impact of politics. In their words: “the extant political equilibrium may crucially depend on the presence of the market failure. Economic reforms implemented without an understanding of their political consequences, rather than promoting economic efficiency can significantly reduce it.”
This work dovetailed with the impressive work of another Nobel laureate, Douglass North, whose book Violence and Social Orders with John Wallis and Barry Weingast, was published in 2009. Acemoglu and Robinson write that the North et al book “also indirectly underscores that the ‘good economics is good politics’ dictum is fallacious by providing several counterexamples in the context of what they call the ‘natural state’,” in which warring elites construct often highly inefficient elite bargains to generate a shared rent pool in exchange for abandoning violence towards one another. The upshot is that policy impositions that are incentive-incompatible with the distribution of political power are unlikely to gain traction.
Delivers both
For this reason, many analysts have argued that democracy does not work for Africa as it has not produced an appropriate economic dividend. Some see it as a Western imposition that is incongruent with postindependence political equilibriums. Others posit, more condescendingly, that African countries are not yet ready for democracy. Indeed, in the context of global democratic backsliding, what should we say to this?
Acemoglu and Robinson’s 2019 book, The Narrow Corridor, shows that democracy is pivotal to the two arms of governance required for sustained broad-based development, independent of context. Imagine two axes: vertically, we have government effectiveness (or the strength and sophistication of the state); and horizontally we have the power of citizens (or the ability of citizens to hold Hobbes’ Leviathan to account). Democracy is the only political system that delivers both.
There are numerous states where governments are relatively effective, but citizens are repressed. These nations will not see the dividends of broad-based economic prosperity. China, for instance, will grow old before it grows rich. Dictators make strategic mistakes (threaten Taiwan, support Russia and North Korea and so on), cook the books and rewrite history to maintain power and keep citizens in subjugation. This arrangement may at first seem efficient but will prove deleterious in the long run.
To dispel further doubts about the causal direction and nature of the relationship between democracy and economic growth, Acemoglu and Robinson, collaborating with Suresh Naidu and Pascual Restrepo, published a 2019 paper in the Journal of Political Economy unequivocally titled “Democracy Does Cause Growth”. In their words: “Our baseline results show that democratisations increase GDP per capita by about 20% in the long run ... The effects are similar across different levels of development and appear to be driven by greater investments in capital, schooling and health.”
Citizen strength
For this reason it continues to be our firmly held belief at Good Governance Africa that democracy is worth fighting for. Our theory of change, informed by The Narrow Corridor, is that strengthening government effectiveness and empowering citizens simultaneously will produce the economic dynamism required to address structural unemployment and poverty. That is because government effectiveness is a function of bureaucratic quality, robust rule of law, effective control of corruption and political stability.
In turn, citizen strength is a function of the extent to which the state upholds civil liberties such as academic freedom, and the civil liberties of expression and association. Only democracy provides the mechanisms, if often imperfect (there is not only one type of democracy), for citizens to demand delivery, and to hold the government to account if it fails to do so.
We live in an international order in which there is no effective supranational body. In the words of Thucydides, “the strong do as they will, and the weak suffer as they must”. The only way to prevent the “weak” from suffering (in continued poverty) is to empower citizens to stand up to the state. That requires building domestic institutions that create the appropriate ecological incentives for a political equilibrium that is responsive to citizens, and an economic equilibrium that delivers dividends for them. International efforts to complement this are to be welcomed, but they should never be seen as replacements.
Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson have made a profound contribution to the fields of economics and political economy. We should take their work seriously as we think about the most effective way to build narrow corridors in our respective countries.
• Harvey is director of research & programmes at Good Governance Africa.
Japan’s Nihon Hidankyo group wins 2024 Nobel Peace Prize
South Korean novelist Han Kang wins Nobel literature prize
Would you like to comment on this article?
Sign up (it's quick and free) or sign in now.
Please read our Comment Policy before commenting.
Most Read
Related Articles
Nobel economics prize goes to inequality researchers
In Hiroshima, Nobel Prize bring survivors hope, sense of duty
Japan’s Nihon Hidankyo group wins 2024 Nobel Peace Prize
Published by Arena Holdings and distributed with the Financial Mail on the last Thursday of every month except December and January.