subscribe Support our award-winning journalism. The Premium package (digital only) is R30 for the first month and thereafter you pay R129 p/m now ad-free for all subscribers.
Subscribe now
Workers lay new pipelines for crude oil, in San Luis, Ecuador. File photo: REUTERS/TITO CORREA
Workers lay new pipelines for crude oil, in San Luis, Ecuador. File photo: REUTERS/TITO CORREA

The term “labour shortage” was Googled more in May than at any other point in the search engine’s history going back to 2004. Headline after headline has cited wage rises, bonuses and other perks that seem to make it a job hunter’s market.

The concept sounds simple — US companies must be struggling to find the employees they need. Yet some labour economists would argue that the picture is incomplete. Employers are unable to find the workers they want at the wages they are willing to pay. Failing to appreciate this distinction could lead to policy errors down the road. It is just one of many popular misconceptions that distort the lens through which US politicians and policymakers view the labour market, with negative consequences for both workers and employers.

In capitalist markets, the laws of supply and demand should make spotting labour shortages relatively straightforward. When there are not enough workers, employers pay more to get them and wages go up. This dynamic is playing out in real time for hourly employees at companies such as McDonald’s and Amazon, which is offering $1,000 signing bonuses and raising average hourly pay in some locations. Competitors eager to retain talent are thus compelled to boost their wages — not only for newly hired employees but existing ones, too, who start to demand more.

Yet quickening wage growth is not the only hallmark of a shortage. The telltale sign is seeing this trend alongside stalling job growth, as Heidi Shierholz, senior economist and policy director at the Economic Policy Institute puts it. Just look at what has been happening in the US leisure and hospitality sector, among the most bruised by the Covid-19 shutdown.

After jobs all but vanished in the throes of the pandemic, we are starting to see a rebound: in May, the sector created 292,000 jobs, far outpacing other corners of the economy and contributing heavily to the overall increase in nonfarm payrolls of 559,000. June data, to be released on Friday, are expected to show still stronger gains. Meanwhile, average weekly earnings have been rising faster than many other industries. In other words, the market is working to resolve a shortage: when employers lift wages, they are able to attract the employees they need, as Shierholz said in a recent podcast. (She also notes that leisure and hospitality wages are only just meeting pre-Covid-19 levels; they are not too high.)

To assess a shortage accurately, though, you need to look beyond industries to specific occupations and locations. In the past, the Bureau of Labor Statistics has used the taxicab queuing model, based on work by English statistician David George Kendall, to deal with the on-again, off-again debate about a shortage of workers in science, technology, engineering and maths (STEM).

In the analogy, employers and job openings can be thought of as taxis, while workers are a line of waiting passengers. Depending on your location, there may be a long line of taxis (say, at the airport), or conversely a long line of passengers (at a hotel). Demand for petroleum engineers in Texas, for example, is different from petroleum engineers in Massachusetts, authors Yi Xue and Richard Larson note.

Then there may be different lines depending on whether you are paying with cash or a credit card, or waiting for an Uber. Much in the same way, there are separate queues for each STEM occupation. Demand for employees with doctorates in mechanical engineering differs from demand for bachelor’s degree earners in the same field, the authors note, while the supply of workers with PhDs in biomedical sciences is distinct from the supply of those with doctorates in physics.

The bottom line is that, whether in STEM or other fields, shortages are not universal. Simultaneous shortages and surpluses can sprout up across the economy at any given point, which is why broad-brush policies can be counterproductive.

One standard response to a labour shortage is to expand the pool of foreign temporary workers, who can fill empty positions quickly. In June, a bipartisan group of House members proposed a bill that would expand the H-2B visa for low-wage jobs, including hospitality, restaurants, seafood and meat processing, landscaping and construction. The same is happening for white-collar work: the US Chamber of Commerce has called to double the cap for H-1B visas, used primarily for tech employees. Yet unemployment rates in industries that overlap with the H-2B visa are still high; and lower-paid guest workers have helped  suppress tech wages for years. Adding more workers could exacerbate both trends.

With immigration now firmly established as a wedge issue, sorting such policies from their consequences has become a hyperpoliticised and impulse-driven process. There is a better way. The UK’s migration advisory committee (MAC), established in 2007, is an independent government agency that relies on a data-driven framework to answer three main questions when seeking to determine whether an occupation faces a shortage:

  • Does the occupation require certain skills?
  • Is there evidence of a shortage?
  • Is it “sensible” to fill those shortages with migrant workers?

The MAC combines macro analysis, based on labour-market data such as wage growth and unemployment rates, with micro analysis, including reports from employers, trade unions and other sources. The closest the US comes to anything like a shortage occupation list is the department of labour’s “Schedule A”. It has just two occupations on it, neither of which have been reassessed in three decades.

While MAC-like commissions are supported by US bipartisan groups and think-tanks, and have been proposed before by lawmakers — as part of a comprehensive immigration reform bill in 2009, and again when it was reintroduced in 2013 — legislation to create one has never progressed.

The MAC’s advice is public and nonbinding: the government can choose to accept or reject its recommendations. Shortly after its inception, the committee examined shortage claims for caretakers of the elderly employed by local governments. The MAC was credited with fostering a better public conversation about wage levels and the role of migrant workers.

In the end, wages rose, albeit too modestly to address some root problems, and the UK accepted more guest workers. The outcome may have been imperfect, but it reflected evidence-based debate and some degree of compromise.

Compare that with what happens in the US, where the conversation is largely driven by businesses trying to influence policy makers behind closed doors, write Daniel Costa of the Economic Policy Institute and Philip Martin, an economics professor at the University of California, Davis. “While the data are sometimes clear, in many cases, shortage determinations are an inexact and subjective science,” Costa wrote in an e-mail. Without a credible source of information and set of objective criteria, we are ceding the debate to the loudest lobbyists with the fattest wallets.

A shortage misdiagnosis can have serious repercussions, particularly if it leads to policies that offer up lower-cost substitutes for US workers and suppress wages. In the early 2000s, right after the dotcom bust, the US Congress raised the H-1B cap to 195,000 from 115,000 (and 65,000 in 1998) to placate demands of the tech industry. Unemployment in computer and mathematical occupations ended up rising steadily and wages flatlined. In the absence of a standard or scientific way to assess whether shortages exist, such errors will be repeated.

Independent commissions have their sceptics, but a formalised debate will be better than the supercharged guesswork we are using now. The cost of miscalculation is too dear to rely on well-funded, self-interested hunches.

Bloomberg Opionion. More stories like this are available on bloomberg.com/opinion

subscribe Support our award-winning journalism. The Premium package (digital only) is R30 for the first month and thereafter you pay R129 p/m now ad-free for all subscribers.
Subscribe now

Would you like to comment on this article?
Sign up (it's quick and free) or sign in now.

Speech Bubbles

Please read our Comment Policy before commenting.